In the interest of offering content both didactic and accessible,
the following Serious Topic will not include proper source support. This means
you shouldn’t believe any of it. If you find the discussion compelling, however,
I encourage you to pursue a more demonstrable truth.
A while ago, I was discussing coupons
with a friend of mine after we had gone grocery shopping.
“Coupons are such a raw deal,” is
something similar to what he said. “They’re like rebates. Stores could just put
on a sale so that everyone would capture the benefits of the savings; instead,
they limit savings to the people who take the time to cut out coupons.”
It’s an interesting thought. I wonder
where coupons come from. I suspect they weren’t born out of advertising for the
store offering the discount at all, because they seem less effective than
normal sales for that. I suspect they were devised as a means of peddling
publications: buy this magazine/newspaper, and you’ll find coupons inside.
Then, of course, the magazine/newspaper pays the store offering its coupons.
How do coupons and sales influence
business? Here’s how I imagine it:
Let’s make up a store called, say,
Supermarket. Supermarket wants to make a profit of $1 million every year, and
has to decide between two different types of savings to offer.
Before offering any discounts, here is
the equation for determining Supermarket’s profit:
(Revenue) – (Costs) = $1 million
Let’s imagine, for the sake of
simplicity, that the Revenue variable is limited to the amount of money
Supermarket gets from selling off its inventory. Let’s also stipulate (again,
for simplicity’s sake) that the Revenue variable is the amount of money that
Supermarket gets for selling the standard amount of inventory—that is, the
amount that it sells when it doesn’t incentivize customers (with discounts) to
buy more (or incentivize new customers to come buy things).
Now for the discounts:
Type 1: Sales. Supermarket discounts items in the store; the net discount is x%. The new formula for profit is:
(Revenue * [1 – x]) + (New sales) – (Costs)
= $1 million
The Revenue variable is smaller because
less money is made off of the baseline sales. However, we need to add a new
variable: New sales. Because things are cheaper, some people buy more stuff,
and some people who used to buy elsewhere start buying at Supermarket. The
result? Supermarket still makes that $1 million, but they charge people less
money on average. Swell!
Type 2: Coupons. Supermarket sends out
coupons that offer discounts to whomever brings in those coupons and buys the
corresponding products, discounted y% (an amount which might, but probably doesn't, equal x). The formula:
(Revenue * [1 – y]) + (New sales) – (Costs)
= $1 million
Yes, it’s the same as the previous
formula. Coupons and sales don’t offer mathematically different outcomes as far
as Supermarket is concerned. But they are materially different options from a
distributive perspective. Take a look:
Let’s theorize that Supermarket knows
that it makes the most money when its customers actually save a total of 10%.
That is, Supermarket is operating in an efficient market, has lots of good
information, and knows that its profit margin is maximized when customers
capture a savings of 10%. All things considered, that's the point at which reducing costs and attracting new sales balances out to the highest gain.
If Supermarket has $1 million of
inventory at any given time, they could just have a sale that discounts
every item by 10%. In this scenario, every customer would capture a savings of
10%--on every item, each person would save 10%. On that $1 million of inventory, that would mean a savings of $100,000, plus more savings on the new sales that would be drawn in due to the sale (what a dismal sentence!).
Alternatively, Supermarket could
discount some items more than 10%, and some items less than 10%. They might
discount fresh produce 50%, cookies 2%, and cigarettes not at all. So long as
the net discount delivers a 10% savings to the customers, this would, in
theory, equal out. Of course, it’s also functionally the same thing. When you
grocery shop, do care about your total bill, not the dollar breakdown. If I
offered to sell you a gallon of milk and a carton of eggs for $5.00, you wouldn’t
care if each cost $2.50 or if the milk cost $4.50 and the eggs $0.50.
Of course, reality turns this logic
upside down for (at least) two reasons. The first is that smart shoppers would
simply buy the highly-discounted items at Supermarket and the others at some
other store that discounts them more; the second is that demographics would
change the customer population at Supermarket. People who buy lots of produce
and don’t smoke would tend to shop there. This self-selective bias would ruin
the profit projections. But hey, this is theory, not reality.
Then there are coupons. If Supermarket
knows that it wants its customers to secure a 10% actual discount rate, it also
knows it needs to send out a quantity of coupons that represents a much larger
rate of savings than 10%. Naturally! Because not all coupons will be used. When
every item is on sale, there’s just no way to avoid saving. But even if
Supermarket sent out coupons for 10% off every item, some people wouldn’t use
them, and the total discount would be lower.
Some people just don’t care about
coupons. Mr. CEO is too rich to care; the time he would spend clipping coupons
is worth more to him than the money he’d save. Then there are some people who
will spend a lot of time clipping coupons because they need to save every penny
they can. These people will touch savings that might greatly exceed 10%. So
essentially, issuing coupons rather than setting general sales allows customers
to do their own cost/benefit analysis and self-select their savings rate. This
naturally means that greater savings are allocated to lower-income
demographics.
Looking at it from this perspective, coupons suddenly seem like a very generous system. It's almost social welfare! Just like our healthcare system (at least as of 2014) and virtually every other social program, coupons take money out of rich peoples' pockets (in the form of missed savings) and put give them to the poor! Weird. And yes; rebates are the same thing. We've all shamefully neglected to send in rebates before. If you did, it's because you could afford to. Someone who really needed that $50 wouldn't have failed to ask for it.
All of this stuff is really hard to
project, of course. Market inefficiencies and transaction costs are important!
For example, producing coupons is not without its costs. This is, I suppose, where economists and accountants get into fights, and why "externalities" is a dirty word in most of my classrooms. What if printing coupons creates lots of chlorofluorocarbons and forces Supermarket to buy expensive carbon offsets on some cap-and-trade market somewhere!?
I also wonder how extreme couponers (these people I’ve seen chronicled on TV who clip coupons as full-time jobs and manage to buy thousands of dollars of groceries for pennies) are influencing this balance.
I’m no business/marketing/economics
expert, clearly. I don’t understand why stores would turn to coupons except for
the seemingly altruistic purpose of redistributing costs away from lower income
individuals. They introduce greater uncertainty (e.g., the percentage of
savings mailed that will be actually used in the store) and higher costs. Perhaps
there are some tax credits available to businesses issuing coupons; that seems
like it would be good policy to me. Or maybe coupons really do convince people
to go to the store and seek out certain products, only to pick up other stuff
as well. I’m sure the devil is in…well, not the details, but real consumer
behavioral trends that my basic theoretical exploration didn’t explore. Altruism
is rarely the motivator in these matters, in any case.
No comments:
Post a Comment