<STD: Serious Topic Disclaimer>
In the interest of offering content both didactic and accessible,
the following Serious Topic will not include proper source support. This means
you shouldn’t believe any of it. If you find the discussion compelling, however,
I encourage you to pursue a more demonstrable truth.
Especially
following the State of the Union address, I’ve been thinking a lot about our
defense spending situation. Of course, the whole point of this blog is to argue
through things with some degree of measure and reason, and the State of the
Union doesn’t do that at all, regardless of the president or his political
leanings. The SOTU is designed to inspire, reassure, and galvanize. Nobody
should treat anything President Obama said during the address as an argument
for any policy point, whether for the sake of supporting or for impeaching that
position. It’s just propaganda. I don’t mean this to sound pessimistic—it’s
just the nature of the beast. Nobody, in an hour and a half, can make a
statement sufficiently comprehensive to be considered a thorough argument of
all the issues confronting our nation.
But that
doesn’t mean important things weren’t discussed, and our defense spending
really is one of the most controversial debates raging at this moment.
Balancing our collective budget is politically a hot button issue, and most
agree that some amount of revenue increase partnered with some amount of
spending cuts will be necessary to accomplish that goal. The trick is finding
out where defense spending fits into that equation, and I think the issue
presents some unique problems.
I’ll
preface my discussion by saying that I recently had the occasion to speak with
someone who is positioned better than perhaps anyone on the planet (except perhaps
the current Secretary of Defense and President Obama) to offer insight on this
issue. Our discussion informs the following. Actually, things I’ve learned over
the past few weeks have changed the way I think about a lot of this stuff.
For a bit
of overview: Currently defense spending sits at around 24% of the U.S. budget,
but budget cuts undertaken over the past few years under Secretary Gates (two
separate cuts of $400 billion each) leave us with a significant anticipated
decrease. Washington is working on the much-maligned sequestrations right now,
which would cut an additional $600 billion. Considering these cuts and rising
costs in other sectors—most notably health care, where costs are projected to
skyrocket and which will likely (in my opinion) even increase at a rate
exceeding expectations—our defense spending is no longer the monster spending
sector archetype a lot of us imagine it to be. Think 15% or so of the budget
for the coming years (though, depending on how other sectors develop and how
much the sequestrations actually cut defense spending, this number could
fluctuate).
So how
much do we need to spend on defense? Or, a better question: How should we
approach this problem? As with virtually every question, there’s a deceptively
simple equation on which we should model our thinking. What are the risks and
what are the costs? In other words, if the cost of increasing defense spending
is less than the cost we expect to incur if we don’t, then we should increase
spending. Conversely, if the costs of decreasing spending are less than the
money we cut, then slash away. This is at least the basic model from which we
should begin an analysis, but things get a lot more complicated, as we’ll soon
see.
The first
problem we encounter relates to information availability. U.S. citizens know
how much money goes into the defense budget—that information is public domain.
Of course, we don’t know what the money buys in a lot of cases (there’s no line
item for “secret government base,” of course), but that’s not so important. The
point is that one half of our equation—the cost of defense spending—is very
easy to measure.
Not so
easy to measure are the expected risks associated with changes in defense
spending. Imagine a hypothetical country approaching this issue. It could opt
to be very defense-oriented, surrounding itself with walls, missile defense
systems, mounted guns, tanks, and all the military infrastructure one could
imagine. It could invest in nuclear weapons and compile a huge arsenal. It
could make military service mandatory. All of these things would certainly make
this country very secure (OK, these things might also be the sign of a crazed
military dictator and create a very unstable relationship with terrified
neighbors, but let’s keep things simple for the sake of this analysis), but
would also be very expensive. Another way of looking at this is that the
hypothetical country could devote 100% of spending to defense, thus effectively
minimizing the risk of loss associated with inadequate defenses. On the other
side of the coin, a country could spend 0 on defense, maximizing potential
loss, but also bearing no defense costs. If nobody ever attacks, they’re great
beneficiaries of their policy; however, if someone does, they’re out of luck
(to put things mildly).
That’s
just the problem, though: How do we know if someone will attack, or whether our
country will be involved when other countries fight? Information gathering is a
big part of defense spending for just this reason. But there’s a lot of
uncertainty here, and that makes the second half of the cost/risk analysis a
lot harder to handle. If our hypothetical country is a place like the United
States, most reasonable people don’t feel
like their lives are in danger. But if it’s a place like, say, Libya, the
opposite might be true. Are these intuitions a good basis on which to judge our
spending habits? Probably not, but we don’t have the information to say they’re
necessarily wrong.
The
alternative is to look at our military intelligence and rely on those risk
projections. There a few problems with this approach, as well. They are,
briefly: Transparency, agency costs, and risk aversion.
1.
Transparency: This one is obvious, and it’s particularly tough because it’s
such a necessary problem. The military has
to operate with some degree of operational confidentiality, or security could
be compromised. Just like police investigators will withhold information from
the public to keep the bad guys in the dark and to gauge the value of new data,
so the military keeps certain things under wraps. We all know it’s true, and we
should all be OK with it to a point—if the military disclosed everything, there
might be serious negative externalities, including a serious reduction in the
efficiency of our defense spending. I’m a big fan of small government, but some
things just make sense, and our system was wisely designed to keep civilians in
control of the military (through the president) precisely so that the military
could do its classified stuff without presenting a threat to the populace.
Regardless,
this makes it really tough for average citizens to gauge what risks we’re
facing. People in the Pentagon probably know about attacks on this country that
have been foiled silently. Pundits on television probably don’t have that
information—nor do a lot of people in our nation’s policymaking circles. But those
risks do factor into the model
equation.
2. Agency
costs: Just like in corporate law (or any scenario where anyone is hired to do
something, really), our top military personnel produce agency costs—and I’m not
just talking about their salaries. There’s the obvious conflict of
interest—people in the military (and especially, perhaps, at the top of it) are
probably more likely to support military action, and thus higher spending. These
people have made a living out of the business of defense, so it’s natural for
them to be devoted to accomplishing those goals. Most people overrate the
importance of what they do, and the military is no different. Of course,
countervailing this effect are the procedural realities checking military power
in the United States (e.g., Congress sets the military budget; the President is
Commander-in-Chief).
The fact
remains, though, that the people in possession of the best information most
relevant to defense spending decisions are also the people who want that
spending the most. They also don’t reveal all of that information to us. And
the market forces pushing these guys do make efficient decisions are weak: How
many people are qualified to be CIA directors, four-star generals, and
secretaries of defense? How many of those people have a realistic shot at the
job? What about all the political considerations? I don’t think the labor
market bears heavily on their decision making process, and I don’t think we
have any good way to measure how much efficiency we lose because of these
actors’ relative lack of accountability.
3. Risk
aversion: This counts as an agency cost in one sense, but also deserves
distinction in a more general sense. Defense spending is usefully analogized to
insurance spending. A young, healthy person might (in a vacuum) opt not to pay
for health insurance. Such a person probably expects to spend very little on
health care, so it makes some sense. He’s done his cost/benefit analysis: The likely
cost of health care is less than the cost of health insurance. Of course,
another important detail is that hospitals may not refuse emergency care. So in
the event of some catastrophic health event, this young, healthy person doesn’t
go untreated for lack of insurance.
The
subject of risk aversion is where the insurance analogy breaks down. We treat
the people in charge of military spending decisions like insurance actuaries.
They weigh the need for protection against its costs, (hopefully) considering the
costs (e.g., the opportunity cost of using that money for defense instead of
for, say, education or welfare) and the risks (e.g., the threat of Iranian and
North Korean nuclear weapons). Actuaries for an insurance company are looking
to maximize profit; they do this by calculating risk as accurately as possible
so that the insurance company can insure as many people as possible, charging
them as little as possible to ensure their business. If the AllState actuary can
find an inefficiency that is making GEICO overcharge its customers, AllState
can steal those customers and turn a bigger profit. But of course, charging too
little would mean that AllState would operate at a loss. In other words,
insurance actuaries are looking to operate at the margin—the most competitive
price. Just like WalMart and K-Mart are going to sell the same product for
pretty close to the same price—as cheap as they can make it and still profit—so
will insurers. But defense spending policymakers aren’t “selling” anything.
They have to pitch their budget to Congress, sure, but that process seems (to
me, as an outsider) more political than anything else. How can we know they’re
properly motivated to act efficiently? Well, in fact, there seems to be a lot
of evidence that they aren’t.
Decision
makers themselves are somewhat risk averse because they will get blamed for
whatever happens, regardless of whether they deserve blame. People lose jobs over
this stuff, and nobody wants to get pegged as the one who let a terrorist
attack happen, for example. All this is true despite our conscious balancing of
costs and risks—we all should know
that reducing risks to 0 is probably impossible, and when we cut costs, risks
usually increase commensurately (of course, this is all subject to all sorts of
other influences, as well). Just like corporate officers are likely to play it
safe on investors’ dimes, so are policy makers who don’t want the next big attack
to happen on their watch.
So that’s
inefficient, but is it necessarily bad? Investors want corporate agents to act
efficiently, even when it means taking risks, because investors have
diversified risks and they gain the most when their investments operate
optimally, even if that means one fails now and again. They’re playing the
market in general—not specific corporate entities. But we as American citizens
aren’t playing the market; we’ve got all of our eggs in this basket. This
brings us to the second point about risk aversion, for which I’ll return to the
insurance analogy.
As I said
before, even the guy who has no health insurance will get treatment if he goes
to the ER—although the cost will be very high. In the real world of defense, however,
there is no hospital that can bail us out. This is really scary when you
consider that these days the “catastrophic health event” is nuclear war.
There’s no safety net to handle that—only preventative measures and practiced
responses, and all of that is really expensive. This sort of thinking is somewhat
alarmist, yes. Nevertheless, it shouldn’t be ignored, when considering this
issue, that included in the “risks” column is a nuclear war whose consequences
could be unfathomable—even if the risk is very small. It’s hard not to be risk
averse in face of such a worst-case scenario, even if it leads to inefficiency.
As a society we consider it moral and responsible to pay for things like life
insurance, even when the odds of dying are very low. It’s interesting to me—and
I don’t mean the term in a loaded sense—that many don’t seem nearly as invested
in insuring our national life, as it were.
So, to
review: When we debate what to do with defense spending, we should keep in mind
that it’s a question of balancing the toll it takes on our budget with the
protective benefits those dollars buy us. The problem with this equation is
that the only people who really know how much protection our money buys us—and
how much we need it—are probably biased, and in any case there are a worryingly
small number of them. It puts the average citizen in a poor position to develop
an informed perspective.
Of course,
one thing on which everyone does seem
to agree is that the $600 billion cut that the sequestration proposes is a bad
idea because it doesn’t give the secretary of defense a chance to plan and
adjust in anticipation. Hopefully we can get that worked out.
No comments:
Post a Comment